Political institutions and the development of telecomunications
- Andonova Zuleta, Veneta
- Díaz Serrano, Luis
Any de publicació: 2006
Número: 10
Tipus: Document de treball
Resum
It has traditionally been argued that the development of telecommunications infrastructure is dependent on the quality of countries¿ political institutions. We estimate the effect of political institutions on the diffusion of three telecommunications services and find it to be much smaller in cellular telephony than in the others. By evaluating the importance of institutions for technologies rather than for industries, we reveal important growth opportunities for developing countries and offer policy implications for alleviating differences between countries in international telecommunications development.
Referències bibliogràfiques
- Andonova, V. (2006). Mobile Phones, the Internet and the Institutional Environment. Telecommunications Policy, 30, 29-45.
- Arellano, M. and S. Bond. (1991). Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277-97.
- Arellano, M. and O. Bover. (1995). Another Look at the Instrumental Variable Estimation of Errorcomponents models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29-51.
- Aschauer, D. (1989a). Is Public expenditure Productive? Journal of Monetary Economics, 23, 177- 200.
- Aschauer, D. (1989b). Does Public Capital Crowd out Private Capital? Journal of Monetary Economics, 24, 171-188.
- Bergara, M., Henisz, W. and P. Spiller. (1998). Political Institutions and Electric Utility Investment: a Cross-Nation Analysis. California Management Review, 40(2), 18-35.
- Berndt, E. and C. Morrison. (1995). High-tech Capital Formation and Economic Performance in U.S. Manufacturing Industries: An Explanatory Analysis. Journal of Econometrics, 65(1), 9- 43.
- Blundell, R. and S. Bond. (1998). Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115-43.
- Bond, S. (2002). Dynamic Panel Data Models: A Guide to Micro Data Methods and Practice. Working Paper 09/02. Institute for Fiscal Studies, London.
- Brynjolfsson, E. and L. Hitt. (1996). Paradox Lost? Firm-level Evidence on the Returns to Information Systems Spending. Management Science, 42(4), 541-558.
- Brynjolfsson, E. and L. Hitt. (2000). Beyond Computation: Information Technology, Organizational Transformation and Business Performance. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4), 23-48.
- Canning, D., Fay, M. and R. Perotti. (1994). Infrastructure and Growth. In Bsaldassarri, M., Paganetto, M. and E. Phelps (Eds.), International Differences in Growth Rates.St. Martins Press, New York, 285-310.
- Chinn, M., & Fairlie, R. (2004). The determinant of the Global Digital Divide: Across-Country Analysis of Computer and Internet Penetration. Center for Global International and Regional Studies, WP 2004-3.
- DuBoff, A. (1980). Business Demand and the Development of Telegraph in the United State, 1844- 1860. Business History Review, 54(4), 461-477.
- Dunne, T., Foster, L., Haltiwanger, L. and K. Troske. (1999). Wage and Productivity Dispersion in U.S. Manufacturing: The Role of Computer Investment. Mimeo, Center for Economic Studies, U.S. Bureau of the Census, Washington, DC.
- Easterly, W. and S. Rebelo. (1993). Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: An Empirical Investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 32, 417-458.
- Esfahani, H. and M. Ramírez. 2003. Institutions, Infrastructure, and Economic Growth. Journal of Development Economics, 70, 443-477.
- Garbade, K. and W. Silber. (1978). Technology, Communication, and the Performance of Financial Markets, 1840-1975. Journal of Finance, 33(3), 819-832.
- Hardy, A. (1980). The Role of the Telephone in Economic Development. Telecommunications Policy, 4(4), 278-286.
- Henisz, W. (2000). The Institutional Environment for Economic Growth. Economics and Politics, 12(1), 1-31.
- Henisz, W. and B. Zelner. (2001). The Institutional Environment for Telecommunications Investment. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 10(1), 123-147.
- ITU (1999). World Telecommunications Development Report. Mobile Cellular.
- Levy, B. and P. Spiller. (1996). Regulations, Institutions and Commitment, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
- Nathaniel, L. (1984). Externalities, Information Costs, and Social Benefit-Cost Analysis for Economic Development: An example from Telecommunications. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 32(2), 255-276.
- North, D. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and the Economic Performance, New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
- Norton, S. (1992). Transaction Costs, Telecommunications, and the Microeconomics of Macroeconomic Growth. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 41(1), 175-196.
- Roller, L. and L. Waverman. (2001). Telecommunications Infrastructure and Economic Development: a Simultaneous Approach. The American Economic Review, 91(4), 909-923.
- Roodman, D. 2005. xtabond2: Stata Module to Extend xtabond Dynamic Panel Data Estimator. Center for Global Development, Washington.
- Sanchez-Robles, B. (1998). Infrastructure Investment and Growth: Some Empirical Evidence. Contemporary Economic Policy, 16, 98-108.
- Warf, B. (1995). Telecommunications and the Changing Geographies of Knowledge Transmission in the Late 20th Century. Urban Studies, 32(2), 361-378.
- Wellenius, B. (1977). Telecommunication in Developing Countries. Telecommunications Policy, 1(4), 289-297.
- Williamson, O. (1988). The Logic of Economic Organization. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 4.
- Windmeijer, F. (2005). A Finite Sample Correction for the Variance of Linear Efficient Two-step GMM Estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126, 25-51.
- Yilmaz, S., Haynes, K. and M. Dinc. (2002). Geographic and Network Neighbors: Spillover Effects of Telecommunications Infrastructure. Journal of Regional Science, 42(2), 339-360.